Page 24 - Upland Families, Elites and Communities
P. 24

Giulio Ongaro and Edoardo Demo


               in the land market in the first half of the fifteenth century was charac-
               terized by ‘a widespread lack of aggregation of plots and [by] a relevant
               fragmentation of the estates’ (Bianchi and Demo 2014, 107). This partially
               changed – but without a real turn – in the second half of the century, when
               a ‘clearer logic of aggregation’ occurred, a logic that continued in the first
               decades of the sixteenth century (Bianchi and Demo 2014, 107).
                 However, this change of approach by the urban families did not lead to
               a modernization of the agrarian contracts; the landowners continued to
               avoid direct participation in the cultivation of the plots, and they usual-
               ly rented out the properties to medium-small farmers, resorting to long-
               term contracts (Bianchi and Demo 2014, 107). It seems that this pattern
               endured in the following decades (Ferrarese 2008, 289; Ongaro 2020); in
               the proceeding centuries the estimi of Schio still show a strong fragmenta-
               tion of the plots. Indeed, even if because of the absence of specific research
               on this topic using the estimi, it is difficult to characterize the distribution
               of the properties, given that the tax surveys recorded only the availability
               of the land (owned or rented) and not just the ownership, arapid look at
               the estimi suggests that almost all the rural families had at their disposal at
               least a small plot for self-sufficiency, while only the richest urban and ru-
               ral families declared larger properties, sometimes with houses where ‘the
               worker lives’ (as is frequently written in the tax surveys). This suggests
               the existence of some plots directly cultivated by the landowners through
               waged workers. Further, this kind of management of the properties was
               not a trait only of the urban estates; looking to the estimi, it seems that the
               wealthy rural landowners also used the same approach, renting out their
               properties to medium-small farmers, who were often also employed by the
               landowners themselves as workforce in the textile sector. In this sense the
               land market, together with the credit market (Corazzol 1979), was a crucial
               instrument for the urban families to tie themselves to the rural elites, and,
               in turn, for the latter to create strong bonds – also of patronage – with the
               other rural families.
                 Thehypothesesonwhatwasproducedonthefarmsareevenmore fragile
               than the ones on the structure of the agrarian properties: on the one hand,
               if we consider the morphology of the territory (as anticipated, mainly hilly
               and mountainous), it is difficult to hypothesize a strong market-oriented
               agricultural production. Quoting Francesco Vianello, in the area close to
               the mountains of the province the terrain is ‘composed of a thin layer of
               rough and melted sediments on a bottom of sterile gravel, it is very perme-
               able and, therefore, quite arid’ (Vianello 2004a, 34). That is, a terrain that


               22
   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   26   27   28   29